The battle lines are hardening. More and more eurozone
governments are calling for the ECB to loosen monetary policy, for example by
directly purchasing government debt in an attempt to bring down borrowing costs
and arrest their slide into slump. For its part, the German government and the
Bundesbank are calling for the ECB to exit the currently loose strategy,
fearing a surge of inflation in Germany. But higher German inflation is the
inevitable flipside of a strategy that places the full cost of adjustment on
the struggling economies. It is also indispensable if the crisis-hit economies
are to rebalance and avoid insolvency. Higher inflation presents formidable
political challenges for Germany, but the alternative is a wave of national
defaults, culminating in either a fully-fledged transfer union or a collapse of
the currency union.
Germany’s strategy for dealing with the eurozone – fiscal
austerity and internal devaluations across the south of the currency union –
can only work if economic activity strengthens (and prices rise) elsewhere in
the currency union. The struggling members of the eurozone (a group that is
steadily increasing in size) are trying to regain price competitiveness by
reducing their costs relative to the rest of the eurozone, and attempting to
reduce public indebtedness by pursuing aggressively pro-cyclical fiscal
policies. The result has been a collapse of inflation in Greece, Ireland and
Portugal and rapidly weakening inflation pressures in Spain and Italy, as they
slide into depression.
The ECB targets inflation of ‘close to but under 2 per cent’
for the eurozone as a whole. Assuming inflation falls to zero in Spain, Italy
and the peripheral trio, and averages around 2 per cent in France and the
Benelux trio (it is unlikely to be any stronger given the headwinds facing
these economies), it follows that inflation in Germany (plus Austria and
Finland) will need to rise to around 4 per cent. The German economy’s growth
prospects are not as strong as many believe, with the OECD, the European
Commission and the IMF forecasting only modest growth over the next few years.
However, the IMF estimates that the German economy is running at close to (or
even above) capacity. The country’s so-called output gap (the difference
between the actual output of an economy and the output it could achieve at full
capacity) is zero and its trend rate of growth (the rate of expansion
consistent with stable inflation) is low.
The current monetary stance is certainly too lose for Germany
given these capacity constraints. Assuming that the German economy is not
derailed by the slump across much of Europe (an admittedly large assumption),
German inflation will start to rise relative to the rest of the eurozone. If
the ECB treats Germany like any other eurozone economy, it will hold eurozone
interest rates at their current levels (or even cut them) irrespective of the
level of German inflation, as long as eurozone inflation as a whole remains on
target. After all, the ECB was sanguine about above average Irish or Spanish
inflation in the run up to the crisis.
In reality, it is a moot point whether the ECB would allow
German inflation to run to 4 per cent. Germany is considered the anchor of the
monetary union. Many at the ECB (and not just those from Germany and core
countries closely aligned with it) believe that higher inflation in Germany
would constitute a loss of price stability, threatening the credibility of the
euro. ECB members will also be aware of the threat that higher German inflation
could pose to the legitimacy of the euro in Germany. The German government won
over sceptical Germans to the euro by promising that the ECB would deliver the
same degree of ‘price stability’ as the Bundesbank. The Bundesbank and the
German government would resent much higher German inflation. A sharp rise
in German prices would almost certainly harden German opposition to other
reforms of eurozone governance, not least any form of debt mutualisation.
But assuming the ECB does treat Germany like any other
eurozone economy, what would happen? Germany could try to tighten fiscal policy
further in an attempt to offset the very weak monetary stance. But it is
unlikely to be any more successful than the Spanish or the Irish were in
nullifying the impact of inappropriately loose monetary policy. Negative real
interest rates in Germany would stimulate economic activity in Germany,
increase the demand for labour and push-up wages. Higher German prices and wages
would help facilitate the necessary adjustments in price competitiveness
between the eurozone economies: the peripheral countries would be able to
reduce their wage costs relative to German ones without having to cut nominal
wages. German costs would rise relative to the rest of the currency union,
removing one of the obstacles to a return to economic growth (and debt
sustainability) across the south of the eurozone. This is how adjustment takes
place within a currency union, and was how Germany managed to engineer such a
large real depreciation (or ‘internal’ devaluation) in the first place –
against a backdrop of robust inflation elsewhere in the currency union. Any
attempt to permanently lock-in the competitiveness gains will simply perpetuate
the crisis.
In a welcome intervention, the German finance minister,
Wolfgang Schaüble, recently argued that German wages should rise more quickly
than in the other eurozone economies as this would help the needed rebalancing
within the eurozone. But such a recognition has yet to permeate official
thinking as a whole, and has not really reached the Bundesbank. There are signs that the Bundesbank accepts that German inflation will need to exceed the eurozone average, but certainly no acknowlegement that the differential needs to be very substantial.
The Germans are proud
of the ‘competitiveness’ eked out within the eurozone. Indeed, they continue to
argue that every other member-state can pursue the same strategy as them.
Germany faces a difficult choice: either it accepts higher
inflation and risks the German electorate’s confidence in the euro, or it paves
the way for a wave of defaults culminating in either a fully-fledged transfer
union or the collapse of the euro.
Simon Tilford is chief economist at the Centre for European Reform.
No comments:
Post a Comment